The cost of a bail-out

24 Mar 2020

Could the global economies bear to simply make the private sector whole? Compensate the private sector for the brutal drop in economic activity that looks increasingly likely? Under a set of highly stylised assumptions we conclude – Yes, some countries could.

Some of the worlds largest economies could and may indeed take important steps in a direction that many consider to be destabilising. But these are not normal times.

About that, «at any cost» – let’s try a thought experiment

Let us assume that activity in the private sector falls by 50% in the second quarter of 2020. What would happen if the government simply decides to keep the private sector whole? What would happen if the government simply borrows the needed amounts in the bond market – presumably issuing 30 year debt at near zero percent.

The first assumption is not as silly as you may think. Respectable companies are adjusting their expectations to GDP in Q2 and it could very well be that we end in the vicinity of a 50% loss.

The idea comes from St Louis Federal Reserve President James Bullard, who obviously is trying to needle US lawmakers into action. See an interview with him here. Obviously, there are problems with his bold “proposition”. What about the public sector who continues to chug along? How should the astronomical amounts be distributed? – how do we get the right money to the right people? And so on.

Yet as an exercise in getting the orders of magnitude right, there is nothing wrong with Bullard’s provocation. Governments and their central banks face the choice whether to simply subsidise the private sector in order to avoid a massive loss of jobs and a loss of demand. Everybody knows that the amounts could end up being very significant.

Most governments obviously are obviously queasy at the idea of writing a huge cheque and then borrow the money to finance it.

Instead they propose some kind of mix of government subsidies and credit facilities offered by the public sector or the central bank. Nothing wrong with that. There can be huge gains by avoiding the destruction of productive capacity that would follow from a deep recession.

A 2020 recession is on our hands. Yesterday IMF conceded here by lowering their Dec 2019 assertion for then “Tentative stabilisation – sluggish recovery?”, to the following:

a recession at least as bad as during the global financial crisis or worse, but we expect recovery in 2021”.

Assumptions

Now in order to examine Bullard’s proposition and therefore to give an impression of the magnitude of the economic loss, we have collected data for the world’s 10 largest economies (and since we hail from the Nordics, we’ve included the Nordic countries as well). In order to get as recent data as possible we have taken data from a number of sources and we have made no checking of the accuracy of the data except that they roughly had to correspond to our preconceived notions about a given country.

This method is known as a “quick and dirty” and we stand by it all the way. Except for China, whose data we do not really believe in, since no independent data source exists. But we have included the official PR data anyway for comparison.

We record all data in USD. We assume that the public sector simply will continue without changes. That public employees will be paid as normal and delayed tax incomes will be booked as a receivable. We use the General Government Expenditure category from OECD as a measure of government weight in the GDP. We assume that GDP in Q2 of 2020 is 25% of the annual GDP in 2019.

Accordingly, we set 12.5% of the private sector GDP of a given country as a proxy for the size of the chock to the country’s GDP in Q2.

Further, we use the most recent numbers for the general government debt in order to see how an aggressive subsidy to the private sector would impact the Debt/GDP ratio in the various countries.

Conclusions

The conclusions are stark. Certain countries could without further problems (except maybe losing a AAA standing at the rating agencies) simply go ahead. China, Germany, South Korea, Australia and the Nordics could make the ginormous subsidy without even coming close to the 90% limit of GDP that many consider as destabilising. (reference, Reinhart & Rogoff This time is different, March 2008)

Germany would jump to above the 60% Debt /GDP ratio the country had imposed on the other EU member states. Tsk, tsk.

USA, France, UK and Spain are in an uncomfortable situation where it would probably be dangerous even in the medium term to make these huge handouts and they must likely resort to a mix of fiscal expenditure aimed at employees of the private sector and credits or loan guarantees to companies.

Italy and Japan would be playing with fire. So far, they have been partially shielded by the fact that their debt is largely held by domestic savers. But in a critical situation their indebtedness certainly could lead to a run on their government debt for a European debt crisis 3.0.

Further, we may learn something not particularly surprising. The chock to the GDP is more severe, the smaller the public sector. Just as conservatives dislike a big public sector in normal times, they should perhaps appreciate it in the current situation.

Would this lead to interest rates/bond yields? Given that it would represent a significant dissaving in the public sector, it would change the global balance between investments and savings. So far, we have had a savings glut and hence low (real) bond yields. That would come to an abrupt end if bail-out programmes were to become the order of the day. So yes, bond yields would increase.

So far for the good and the bad.

Now for the ugly: what will it look like if we have not managed to get the coronavirus under some kind of control by 1 July 2020? Will we then look at a similar situation in Q3?

Since we have on several occasions dabbled in scaremongering, we remind readers of IMF’s report of November 2019 where the organisation pointed out that if a recession would be half as bad as that of 2008-9, trouble would be brewing in corporate credits. We are past that point now.

 

GDP 2019 (USD) ‘000 Public sector % of GDP Private sector (USD) ‘000 Chock to GDP (USD) ‘000 Public sector debt (USD) ‘000 Debt/GDP Cost of stimulus as % of GDP Debt/GDP
post stimulus
USA 21,427,199 37.90% 13,306,291 1,663,286 22,700,000 106% 7.8% 114%
China 14,140,000 34.10% 9,318,260 1,164,783 7,518,360 53% 8.2% 61%
Japan 4,971,767 39.40% 3,012,891 376,611 10,181,200 205% 7.6% 212%
Germany 3,863,344 44.00% 2,163,473 270,434 2,319,500 60% 7.0% 67%
UK 2,743,586 42.30% 1,583,049 197,881 2,378,600 87% 7.2% 94%
France 2,707,074 56.80% 1,169,456 146,182 2,684,700 99% 5.4% 105%
Italy 1,988,636 50.30% 988,352 123,544 2,677,600 135% 6.2% 141%
Australia 1,450,000 36.20% 925,100 115,638 629,000 43% 8.0% 51%
South Korea 1,408,870 30.40% 980,574 122,572 581,600 41% 8.7% 50%
Spain 1,397,870 43.90% 784,205 98,026 1,207,750 86% 7.0% 93%
Sweden 531,498 49.50% 268,406 33,551 181,700 34% 6.3% 40%
Norway 402,023 49.30% 203,826 25,478 163,100 41% 6.3% 47%
Denmark 352,058 54.50% 160,186 20,023 117,900 33% 5.7% 39%
Finland 269,714 56.50% 117,326 14,666 162,000 60% 5.4% 66%

 

Your risk manager may need help

Your risk manager may need help

In August 2022 it became mandatory for IFMs (ManCos and AIFMs) to integrate Sustainability Risk in their risk management. The modified level 2 directives and regulations concerning UCITS and AIFs...

SFDR Article 6 Opt-out explained

SFDR Article 6 Opt-out explained

Exegesis is usually reserved for religious scholars trying to extract the last drop of meaning from sacred texts. Most of the sacred texts of the ESG are accompanied by detailed instructions on how...

A house of cards?

A house of cards?

Lately, the US Federal Reserve has acknowledged having misjudged the timing, size and staying power of inflation and consequently accelerated monetary tightening. Should the broader finance market...